Research Article |
Corresponding author: Restiatun Restiatun ( restiatun@untan.ac.id ) © 2024 Eddy Suratman, Restiatun Restiatun.
This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY 4.0), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited.
Citation:
Suratman E, Restiatun R (2024) Consumption smoothing, the cost of children, and family size desired in poor households: empirical evidence from family planning villages in Sintang Regency, the Province of West Kalimantan, Indonesia. Population and Economics 8(3): 156-171. https://doi.org/10.3897/popecon.8.e108790
|
There are many factors that may prevent individuals from achieving consumption smoothing, especially for poor individuals or households. Liquidity barriers for the poor can be overcome by pension programs financed by the government and intergenerational transfers. This research aims at investigating determinants of the family size decisions in poor households. This research uses primary data from survey questionnaires conducted among 447 poor households selected in Family Planning Villages throughout Sintang Regency. The family size decision is only affected by parents’ expectation of an intergenerational transfer. This variable has a significant positive effect, and the possibility of an old-age pension scheme provided by the government does not significantly affect the family size decision. This may be due to the fact that there has been no pension scheme for poor households in Indonesia. The cost of children does not influence the poor household’s family size decision. This is probably due to family package assistance provided by the government which can help reduce the cost of children. The cost of daily living, health and education costs have a significant positive effect on the burden of these costs. The findings of this study indicate that the family assistance package provided by the government does not encourage poor households to have a larger family, meaning that the provision of family assistance packages does not contradict the Family Planning Program. It also provides evidence that the government’s pension scheme for poor households can be also considered as a means of controlling the population growth, because this scheme will lower the expectation of poor households to receive intergenerational transfers.
intergenerational transfer, cost of children, consumption smoothing, pension scheme, poor household
One way to improve people’s welfare and reduce poverty at the macro level is to suppress population growth, for example through a family planning program (
A method households can follow to prepare for consumption smoothing at retirement is saving while still productive (
Liquidity barriers for the poor can be overcome by altruism and philanthropic endowments providing social support for poor households (
The above statement underscores the assumption that there is a positive causal relationship between poverty and fertility at the national and household levels (
Indonesia is one of the low-income countries with the fourth largest population in the world. The World Bank projects that the poverty rate in Indonesia in 2020 will increase by 10.7% in a mild and 11.6% in severe scenarios. It is estimated that there will be 5.5-8 million new poor people since 2019 (Jayani 2020). A report from Worldometers noted that Indonesian population reached 274.86 million as of December 14th, 2020. This number ranks Indonesia fourth in terms of the population size in the world (Annu 2020). To overcome complex problems related to poverty and high population growth, the government has carried out several strategies, such as launching a Family Planning Village program since 2016. The implementation aims to bring a family planning program closer to the community, especially in poor, densely populated urban, fishing villages, slums, and other disadvantaged areas (
On the other hand, the government also provides family assistance packages for poor households, with the aim to improve quality of their lives (
Nationally, 5,590,724 people in Indonesia remain in extreme poverty. Meanwhile, the number of extreme poor people in West Kalimantan Province adds up to 73,342 people or 1.41 percent of the population (Central Bureau… 2023). The number of poor people in West Kalimantan in September, 2022, equaled to 6.81 percent, while at the national level it was 9.36 percent. Sintang’s poverty rate in 2022 is above the provincial level, yet below the national one, which is 8.57 percent (Central Bureau… 2023). In the same year, Sintang’s multidimensional poverty rate was the worst (22.27%) in the province of West Kalimantan (
Education and health care access is expected to increase human resource quality, particularly for children from low-income households, and protect them from falling into poverty. (
Data show that an increase in the provision of pensions for older people by the state correlates with a decline in fertility (
Based on the above explanation, studying determinants of the family size desired by poor households is interesting. This is determined by the expectation of receiving intergenerational transfers from children in retirement or high direct cost of childcare. The more children, the higher the intergenerational transfer that can be expected, but on the other hand it also increases the cost of children before these children enter the labor market, ceteris paribus. And the limitations of poor households in financing their children’s education will cause their children to also be trapped in poverty because the academic abilities of children from poor households are usually low. Limiting the number of children as a condition for obtaining an old-age pension from the government may be an effective way to control population size and poverty.
Regardless of the community type, most couples of childbearing age balance the cost of having children and the expectations of the economic, social, and psychological benefits (
According to a Nigerian study, poverty can affect economic expectations during crisis, hence they have a lower fertility preference (
The individual or household’s ability to respond to uncertainty and cope with income shocks reflects an important life dimension. Furthermore, welfare is enjoyed by individuals or households at a certain point in time. Households with a high risk of being poor are the same as those with low consumption smoothing capabilities. Meanwhile, households with savings for retirement have a lower risk of poverty and a higher ability to smooth consumption. High poverty risks are found in households with a high number of children and dependency burden (
The relationship between demographic structure and household saving rates can be explained through two mechanisms, first, through reducing the number of children who are household dependents to have a higher ability to save. Second, through the composition effect, most of the savings are generated from the difference in income and consumption of the productive population (20 – 65 years old), who mostly receive income from work. Changes in the structure will increase savings in aggregate (
Fertility behavior can be analyzed within the framework of a neoclassical economic model such as developed by Leibenstein in 1957. This model emphasizes the importance of intergenerational transfer as a form of old-age security and fertility motivation in developing countries. In 1960, Becker further developed this model by reconciling predictions from the demand theory in income to increase the demand for children. This paradox was answered by applying the theory of consumer behavior determined by variations in household income and the opportunity costs of childcare.
The Microeconomic Theory of Household Fertility explains that every family has costs and benefits in determining the desired family size. This theory adopts the conventional consumer behavior theory. Children are considered consumer goods (no profit). A demand for children is a rational economic choice. The desire to have children is influenced by income, the cost of living, and the desire to consume other goods, and the demand for children is positively related to income. This is negatively related to the relative cost of children and preferences for other goods (Todaro, 2000).
Meanwhile, the demand for children has qualitative and quantitative dimensions. Hence, the total expenditure is equal to the number of children multiplied by the quality per child and by a price index reflecting the cost of inputs. In the quality – quantity model, spending on children tends to increase with income. However, this is due to the increased child quality, while fertility does not vary based on income variations.
This research uses primary data collected through survey questionnaires. The population is couples from poor households in Family Planning Villages in Sintang Regency, The Province of West Kalimantan. The total sample includes 447 poor households, and the sample was obtained from 15 Family Planning Villages in Sintang regency. Furthermore, a purposive random sampling was used, where the sample size was determined based on the number of residents of the Family Planning Villages selected. The research samples are presented in Table
No. | Family Planning Village | Number of Couples from poor households | Total Sample |
1. | Mungguk Bantok | 9201 | 36 |
2. | Kerapan Sepan | 4702 | 32 |
3. | Pegal Baru | 8399 | 35 |
4. | Sungai Pukat | 1806 | 20 |
5. | Ransi Dansi | 5981 | 30 |
6. | Baya Mulya | 2841 | 20 |
7. | Nanga Jetak | 4940 | 30 |
8. | Baung Sengatap | 3855 | 30 |
9. | Telaga Satu | 2138 | 20 |
10. | Repak Sari | 5983 | 34 |
11. | Jaya Sakti | 3961 | 31 |
12. | Empoyang | 3611 | 33 |
13. | Landau Barat | 3236 | 32 |
14. | Nanga Tonggoi | 3511 | 33 |
15. | Menaong Baru | 4175 | 31 |
TOTAL | 68.340 | 447 |
All data collected will be analyzed using a regression analysis. In this research, the dependent and independent variables are binary. The variables used are binary or dummy variables with values of 0 and 1. Therefore, the estimation equation used to test the relationship between these variables is as follows:
CC i = α0 + α1SABi + α2SAHi + α3SAEi + εi,(1)
FSDi = β0 + β1ITi + β2CCi + β3PGi + ei.(2)
Insert equation (1) in (2), therefore
FSDi = β0 + β1ITi + β2(α0 + α1SABi + α2SAHi + α3SAEi + εi) + β3PGi + ei =
= β0 + β1ITi + β2α0 + β2α1SABi + β2α2SAHi + β2α3SAEi + β2εi + β3PGi + ei =
= (β0 + α0β2) + β1ITi + β2α1SABi + β2α2SAHi + β2α3SAEi + β3PGi + (β2εi + ei) =
= γ0 + γ1SABi + γ2SAHi + γ3SAEi + β1ITi + β3PGi + θi.(3)
Where
FSD : Desired family size
IT : Intergenerational Transfer
PG : Pension Scheme provided by the Government
CC : Direct Cost of Childcare
SAB : Government assistance in basic needs packages
SAH : Government assistance in the health sector
SAE : Government Assistance in the field of education
e, θ, ε : Error term
The operational definitions of the variables in this research are presented in Table
Variable | Description | Value |
---|---|---|
FZD | Number of children planned to be born by couples of childbearing ages. | Children. |
IT | Dummy describes the respondents’ expectations of intergenerational transfer when they enter the retirement age. | Value = 1 if the expected budget for consumption in retirement comes from children; and value = 0 when the budget expectations for consumption in retirement are not from their children. |
CC | A dummy that describes the respondents’ perceptions concerning the burden of the direct cost of children. | Value = 1 when the direct cost of children, which consists of clothing, food, and board costs, education costs, and health care costs for children is considered expensive; and value = 0 when the direct cost of children consisting of clothing, food, and board costs, education costs, and health care costs for children is perceived as inexpensive. |
PG | A dummy that describes the respondents’ perceptions concerning the expectation of a pension scheme provided by the government at an old age. | Value = 1 when there is an expectation of a pension from the government for old age; and value = 0 when there is no expectation of a pension from the government for old age. |
SAB | Dummy describes the respondents’ perceptions concerning the effect of social assistance packages in the form of basic needs packages provided by the government on the direct cost of childcare. | Value = 1 when it is felt that the existence of a social assistance package in the form of a basic needs package provided by the government can reduce the direct cost of childcare; and value = 0 when it is felt that the social assistance package provided by the government in the form of a basic needs package is unable to reduce the direct cost of childcare. |
SAH | Dummy describes the respondents’ perceptions concerning the effect of social assistance packages in the health sector provided by the government on the direct cost of childcare. | Value = 1 when it is felt that the social assistance package in the health sector provided by the government can reduce the direct cost of childcare; and value = 0 when it is felt that the social assistance package provided by the government in the health sector is unable to reduce the direct cost of childcare. |
SAE | A dummy that describes the respondents’ perceptions concerning the effect of social assistance packages in the education sector provided by the government on the direct cost of childcare. | Value = 1 when it is felt that the social assistance package in the education sector provided by the government can reduce the direct cost of childcare; and value = 0 when it is felt that the social assistance package provided by the government in the field of education is unable to reduce the direct cost of childcare. |
The respondent characteristics relate to their socioeconomic background: age, education level, income, number of children, marriage length, and religion. The average age of the husband and wife is 43.39 and 39.31 years, respectively, with the oldest age of 79 years for husband and 76 years for wife. The youngest husband and wife respondents are 17 and 18 years, respectively. Table
The marriage length, as long as the wife is of a childbearing age, will determine the number of children in the household. Based on the marriage length, the average is 18.01 years, with the longest and shortest ones being 48 years and 1 year, respectively.
The average number of children planned and owned is 2.47 and 2.27, respectively. Based on these two averages, the average number of children in poor households is still smaller than the number planned due to a high cost of childcare. There are 33 poor households with the over-than planned number, while the rest have children equal to or less than the planned number. A total of 346 respondents stated that childcare was expensive, and the remaining 101 stated that it was inexpensive. Furthermore, five reported that the most expensive component was health-associated costs, while 166 stated it was the education cost. The remaining 175 respondents named the cost of daily living. Out of the respondents who stated that the cost was inexpensive, four reported that the cheapest component was health-associated costs, while 42 named the education cost. The remaining 55 respondents named the cost of daily living. The complete data are presented in Table
Education is still believed to be one of the tools that can lift children from poor households (
A village can become a Family Planning Village (i.e. participating in the Family Planning Village Program) because most of its population is attributed to the poor. However, because the Indonesian Ministry of Social Affairs (pkh.kemensos.go.id) has established various criteria for qualifying low-income families to receive assistance packages, not all low-income homes in Family Planning Village receive government assistance packages. Out of all the respondents, 181 households received assistance packages from the government, while the remaining 266 did not. About 179 respondents of the assistance recipients stated that the assistance package reduced costs associated with childcare. In comparison, the remaining 2 respondents stated that it did not reduce the current cost of childcare.
Contraceptive devices are a means of planning a family size. There are 310 households using contraception, while 137 are not. This is because there are households where both wives and husbands are old. There are 180 couples of childbearing age, especially households with wives aged under 35. Out of the respondents included in the group of fertile age couples, 127 households use contraception, and the remaining 53 do not. Some couples of childbearing ages do not use contraception, it is possible that they still want to increase their number of children. Meanwhile, there are some couples who are no longer of childbearing age who still use contraception, perhaps to ensure that they no longer get pregnant. Several couples of non-childbearing age were also used as samples with the aim of finding out whether the children they currently have match the number of children they wanted when they were still of childbearing age. For a sample of couples of childbearing age, if there is a discrepancy between the number of children they have and the number of children planned, it is still possible that in the future they will still increase the number of children they have, as long as they are still of childbearing age.
According to
It will be difficult for the impoverished households with extremely low earnings to set aside a portion of their income for retirement savings. Due to the realization that every person should continue to consume after retirement, some impoverished households construct pension plans from their assets, such as rice fields or gardens. These impoverished households believe they can sell these assets to sustain themselves in retirement. Out of all the respondents, 97 stated that they had savings for retirement, while the remaining 350 did not have any savings.
The intergenerational transfer is a source of financing for poor households in retirement. Furthermore, 276 expect an intergenerational transfer at an old age, while the remaining 171 did not expect a transfer. The livelihoods of poor households are employment in the informal sector, where there are no jobs that ensure old-age security or pension funds for workers. Therefore, they may receive pension funds when the government provides for poor households. Out of all the respondents, 222 expect pension funds from the government in retirement, while the remaining 225 do not expect any assistance. Table
Age | Wife | Husband | TOTAL |
15–25 | 39 | 17 | 56 |
26–35 | 142 | 98 | 240 |
36–45 | 151 | 159 | 310 |
46–55 | 75 | 107 | 182 |
56–65 | 32 | 54 | 86 |
66–75 | 7 | 10 | 17 |
> 76 | 1 | 2 | 3 |
Total | 447 | ||
Average age | 39.31 | 43.39 |
Perception of the Cost of Children | The Most Expensive Component | Total | ||
Education | Health | Cost of living | ||
Expensive | 166 | 5 | 175 | 346 |
Inexpensive | 42 | 4 | 55 | 101 |
Total | 208 | 9 | 230 | 447 |
Households from couples of childbearing and non-childbearing ages by category, use of contraceptives and number of children
Household Category | Contraception | Number of children | Total | |
Couples of childbearing ages | Use contraception | Children ≤ 2 | 127 | 127 |
Children > 2 | 24 | 24 | ||
No contraception | Children ≤ 2 | 48 | 48 | |
Children > 2 | 5 | 5 | ||
Couples of non-childbearing ages | Use contraception | Children ≤ 2 | 101 | 101 |
Children > 2 | 82 | 82 | ||
No contraception | Children ≤ 2 | 52 | 52 | |
Children > 2 | 32 | 32 | ||
Total | 447 | 447 |
Table
Even though the variable of the cost of children is insignificant, all cost components are perceived as expensive by low-income families, as seen in Table
Among the components of childcare, health care cost accounts for the largest part of the total cost. The health care cost for children is directly proportional to the probability of households to perceive that childcare costs are expensive. The Indonesian government has been providing health assistance for poor households through health insurance for the poor (Askeskin), and the launch of the Healthy Indonesia Card is expected to increase access to health services. With this increase in access to health care, the health status of the disadvantaged households will improve. Therefore, the labor productivity of poor households is always high (
Education costs are the second highest share of the cost of children. The cost of education for children is proportional to the probability perceived by households. For education expenditure, the government has also provided assistance through BOS (School Operational Assistance) funds and by launching the Smart Indonesia Card (KIP). Children’s access to formal education will increase the education participation rate and decrease dropout cases. Therefore, the next period will increase their access to jobs with better incomes (
The daily living cost component is the variable with the smallest share in the total cost of children. The cost of daily living for children is directly proportional to the probability of households perceiving those childcare costs are expensive. The small share of this daily living cost in the total cost of children is probably because it is often financially minimal. However, households have sufficient food resources on a subsistence basis and can meet their daily needs. Based on the Prob (F statistic) value, all independent variables are significant regressors for childcare costs.
Variable | Coeff | t-stat | Prob |
C | 1.521033 | 13.46572 | 0.0000 |
IT | 1.339433 | 15.74532* | 0.0000 |
PG | -0.046142 | -0.559065 | 0.5764 |
CC | -0.015514 | -0.132330 | 0.8948 |
R-squared | 0.362999 | ||
F-statistic | 84.14874 | ||
Prob (F-statistic) | 0.000000 |
Variable | Coeff | t-stat | Prob |
C | -2.083337 | -6.050148 | 0.0000 |
SAB | 2.488215 | 6.524329* | 0.0000 |
SAH | 3.003321 | 7.260169* | 0.0000 |
SAE | 2.827038 | 7.390292* | 0.0000 |
McFadden R-squared | 0.683611 | ||
LR statistic | 326.5591 | ||
Prob (LR statistic) | 0.000000 |
Every individual or household is expected to perform consumption smoothing upon retirement. For poor households without retirement savings or pension funds, the source of income can be in the form of intergenerational transfers or an old-age assistance scheme provided by the government. Furthermore, these two variables significantly influence decision-making regarding the desired family size. The expectation of an intergenerational transfer is directly proportional to the desired family size. There are high welfare expectations among poor households at the time of retirement when they have a large family size. Meanwhile, the government pension transfer variable has a negative effect on the desired number of children. The poor households in Family Planning Villages in Sintang Regency have not considered the government pension scheme variable in making family size decisions, probably because there is no pension scheme for the poor in Indonesia. This indicates that providing government pension transfers can be a strategy for controlling the population, but the provision is certainly not without conditions. This requirement to obtain assistance is used to control the population. For example, only households with two children will receive pension assistance from the government. However, data are taken from poor households with children, so this can be biased because family size planning is more appropriate for individuals or households that do not have children. Future research can be conducted on couples without children or individuals from poor households who are matured, yet not married.
Annu CM (2020) Indonesia is 4th rank in country with highest population density. URL: https://databoks.katadata.co.id/datapublish/2020/12/15/indonesia-peringkat-ke-4-negara-berpenduduk-terbanyak-dunia (in Indonesian)
Badan Kepegawaian Negara (2023) Batas usia pension PNS. URL: https://betv.disway.id/read/17293/terbaru-bkn-resmi-tetapkan-batas-usia-pensiun-pns-2023-bukan-56-tahun-lagi-berapa-itu (in Indonesian)
BKKBN (2022) Kampung KB di Indonesia. Badan Koordinasi Keluarga Berencana Nasional.
Cabinet Secretariat of Republic Indonesia. (2021) Gov’t Launches Cash Social Assistance Programs for 2021. URL: https://setkab.go.id/en/govt-launches-cash-social-assistance-programs-for-2021/ (in Indonesian)
Central Bureau of Statistics of Indonesia (2023) Indonesia in figures. URL: https://www.bps.go.id/en
Jayani DH (2020) World Bank Projection for The Indonesian poverty level until 2020. URL: https://databoks.katadata.co.id/datapublish/2020/07/21/proyeksi-bank-dunia-kemiskinan-indonesia-2020-bisa-sampai-11 (in Indonesian)
MediaBUMN (2023) Direksi Anak Perusahaan BUMN, Erick Thohir Hapus Syarat Batas Usia. URL: https://mediabumn.com/direksi-anak-perusahaan-bumn-erick-thohir-hapus-syarat-batas-usia (in Indonesian)
Eddy Suratman – Lecturer and Researcher at Universitas Tanjungpura, Faculty of Economics and Business. Pontianak, The Province of West Kalimantan, 78124, Indonesia. Email: eddy.suratman@ekonomi.untan.ac.id
Restiatun Restiatun – Corresponding author, Lecturer and Researcher at Universitas Tanjungpura, Faculty of Economics and Business. Pontianak, The Province of West Kalimantan, 78124, Indonesia. Email: restiatun@untan.ac.id